The bestselling co-author of Why Nations Fail and the bestselling co-author of 13 Bankers deliver a bold reinterpretation of economics and history that will fundamentally change how you see the world
A thousand years of history and contemporary evidence make one thing clear. Progress depends on the choices we make about technology. New ways of organizing production and communication can either serve the narrow interests of an elite or become the foundation for widespread prosperity.
The wealth generated by technological improvements in agriculture during the European Middle Ages was captured by the nobility and used to build grand cathedrals while peasants remained on the edge of starvation. The first hundred years of industrialization in England delivered stagnant incomes for working people. And throughout the world today, digital technologies and artificial intelligence undermine jobs and democracy through excessive automation, massive data collection, and intrusive surveillance.
It doesn’t have to be this way. Power and Progress demonstrates that the path of technology was once—and may again be—brought under control. The tremendous computing advances of the last half century can become empowering and democratizing tools, but not if all major decisions remain in the hands of a few hubristic tech leaders.
With their breakthrough economic theory and manifesto for a better society, Acemoglu and Johnson provide the vision needed to reshape how we innovate and who really gains from technological advances.
Daron Acemoglu is the Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. In 2005 he won the prestigious John Bates Clark medal, awarded to the best economist under 40.
Two American economists reinterpret a thousand years of history and technological progress. The evidence shows that technology (as with most other things) has all too often benefited the elites and made others worse off. Progress is not automatic, and it is dependent on choices made as a society. Using the lessons from the past, society must reshape the path of innovation to create shared prosperity for all.
It feels impossible to escape the current hype about artificial intelligence. And while I am no expert on AI technology, I do have a strong curiosity about the uses for AI and find myself wondering often what it will look like in the future…hence my interest in this book. The authors' reinterpretation of the last 1,000 years of human development supports the somewhat unsettling conclusion that technology does not always equal progress. The book pulls examples from the agricultural technologies of the neolithic and medieval ages, the building of the Panama Canal, the rise of middle class entrepreneurs during the Industrial Revolution, and how banks got to be thought of as too big to fail during the financial crisis. A lot of these examples offered a new layer of understanding to what I already knew about these time periods or events. I also found the authors' analysis of automation to be particularly compelling with the exploration of so-so automation ("all the displacement and little of the promised productivity gains"). Finally, I walked away with a lot to consider about future AI developments based on the authors' roadmap of how the benefits of the next technological wave can be shared with everyone.
The two authors are economics professors, so you can expect that the writing is heavy on the research and light on the narrative storytelling. The book is still very readable, but it is definitely not concise. The authors reinforce their points over and over, so the content starts to feel quite repetitive a few chapters in. I found the ideas and messages of the book to be really interesting, but I wish there had been a little more editing. I think the book could have been about 200 pages shorter just by removing all of the repetition without sacrificing any of the critical messaging and ideas.
I gained some new perspectives on technological progress, and I learned quite a bit from the historical case studies included in the book. However, due to the unnecessary length, this probably isn't one I would actively recommend to others, but it's still an interesting read for anyone with a strong interest in technology, AI, and/or automation.
Ever wondered how tech revolutions, from the humble plow to today's smartphones, impacted the average person? Well, 'Power and Progress' is like this time-traveling tour, stopping at all the big game-changing moments: farming breakthroughs, steam power, the huge buzz of the Industrial Revolution, and of course, our modern smartphone craze. But here's the kicker – the book doesn't just geek out over the gadgets and innovations; it dives deep into who really got the better end of the deal. Did the big shots and aristocrats cash in all the chips? Or did the everyday people see some of the action? Acemoğlu's takes us on a ride through history's tech rollercoaster.
Acemoğlu's writing style, for starters, is captivating. There's this refreshing balance between depth and approachability. Some authors delve so deep into academic jargon that you feel like you need a PhD to understand them. Not here. Daron manages to serve up a scholarly feast that's easy on the palate, ensuring you grasp the key points without feeling overwhelmed.
One of my favorite sections dives into the Industrial Revolution. We've all learned about it in school, but Acemoğlu provides fresh insights, explaining not just the “what” but the “why.” Why did some societies flourish during this period while others seemed to stagnate? His answers, deeply rooted in the interplay of power dynamics, technological change, and institutional structures, give a fresh perspective on this critical epoch.
Another highlight is his analysis of modern technological advancements, especially when it comes to AI and automation. We're living in an era where the pace of technological progress is, frankly, mind-boggling. Acemoğlu raises smart questions about how these shifts will influence labor markets, income distribution, and social structures. He doesn't pretend to have all the answers, but his explorations are thought-provoking and timely.
Now, don’t get me wrong, this isn’t a light read you’d pick up for a beach day. But if you're up for something a bit more cerebral, something that challenges you to think about the world around you and the future that awaits, “Power and Progress” is a worthy choice.
There are just so many insights in this book that are brand new. It offers a rich, insightful look into the complicated relationship between technology, societal structures, and prosperity. It's a blend of history, economics, and foresight, all wrapped up in an engaging narrative. Whether you're a student, an academic, or just a curious soul looking for a meaningful read, this one's really compelling. I learned a lot.
I had high hopes for this book, given the intelligence and expertise of the authors, but was sorely disappointed.
I was hoping for a model of how to think about the distribution of productivity gains from technological change. Instead, there's a parade of extreme of anecdotes of productivity gains not being widely shared through society. The case of communist China and the Soviet Union should be directly applicable to the situation our economy might face, right? Well, no.
There is much discussion about the history of economic growth. The book does not go into detail but blithely dismisses the explanations that (I think) are widely accepted in the academic profession without much support. Probably the authors should go read _How the World Became Rich_, a book with well-argued and well-referenced modern research. The authors need not agree but without better support of their positions (without SOME support of their positions) there's really no justification for accepting their positions.
The authors repeatedly make the same advice: think about the people when taking actions that affect technological progress. Just that, nothing more specific. Why might people/companies NOT already have those thoughts? If there are such reasons, why do they make the choices that they do and what would be required to change those choices? The book is mostly silent on this and thus no particular help: if you're someone who's already thought a tiny bit about the issues faced you won't find anything here to help you think about the potential problems any more clearly.
The book does point to how the German economy has handled such problems, the authors should go back and read their colleague Autor's book _The Work of the Future_ to understand the complications and limitations of introducing such a system to the US. In fact, if you're reading this review, you should probably Autor's book over this one: it doesn't promise to cover the ground of _Power and Progress_ but at least it covers its related material well and, even though imperfect, it may increase your understanding of the coming changes and how to think about them.
2.5, thesis point interesting and uses some cool case studies but over-all not my cup of tea, primarily because I think it could have been much shorter
Part of the 2 star rating is that I think it could have been a lot better, so while I'm really on the fence between 2 and 3, I'm rounding down as a "missed opportunity" penalty. I wouldn't have bothered to write such a long review if I didn't have a lot of respect for Acemoglu and think a lot of what they're arguing about is important
TLDR I wouldn't reccomend this book to anyone. You'd only be persuaded of the thesis if you already agreed.
Basically the book has a plausible thesis; technology doesn't necessarily benefit humanity. There are obvious contexts in which this is true (e.g. inside authoritarian regimes). There are also more controvercial cases where it's very complicated (e.g. automation, social media).
There are at least four serious problems with how the authors argue in this book. In all cases I'm not even saying they are wrong, just that they aren't persuasive.
First, they don't actually state who or what matters. This is really important, say in the case of labour unions, since (if all goes well) labour unions being powerful likely helps wages for [employed, unionised] workers, at the expense of something. That something might be less business profits for the rich (presumably what society wants), or it might be - Higher prices for consumers - Less total jobs - Less prefits for shareholders (some of whom are rich others might be pension funds) - If union power leads to say less offshoring it might mean jobs go to Americans that would have gone to people in the developing world. (Probably all of these things happen to varying extents). The implicit assumption of the authors based on what they paint as 'good' and 'bad' outcomes is that American workers are all that matter. I don't think the authors actually believe thisl; my point is just that whether say labor unions slowing automation is good depends on heaps of complicated dynamics, and how we allocate moral value, and the authors at least for the sake of the book seem uninterested in delving down into the complicated dynamics. For someone like me who's philosophical intuition is that "all people matter basically equally" reading chapters like this offers almost nothing.
Secondly, the authors seem to ignore other plausible approaches to fix the (sometimes very real) problems they point out. For example, if automation hurts jobs we have at least two possible approaches. One is we can encourage/force companies to use labor they don't need. Another is we could have a robust social safetly net such that people out of jobs are supported (e.g. UBI, negative income tax, job training programs). There are some reasons to favour the former; less distruption, jobs are good for mental health etc. There might also be good reasons to consider that latter: - If we're wrong and the labour market will adapt, then we aren't locking ourselves in an inefficient way of doing things. Few poeple lament that there aren't many weavers, or that relatively few of us need to be farmers, even though when these sectors were distrupted we worries about the same things we are now. - The overall efficiency is likely to be higher without distorting incentives, so there is in theory more actual stuff to redistribute. - A policy of redistribution is less complicated than trying to regulate automation, so it's less likely policy will make a mistake and cause harm For the most part the authors don't even entertain these kinds of market based or welfaree based alternatives, so if they have good reason to prefer direct regulation on automation they don't tell me what it is. In the very final chapter they very superficially touch on some of these alternatives, but unhelpfully. E.g. they they dismiss UBI in about two sentences on the gounds that it's not targeted and might lead to less people working. Now I'm not some pro UBI zeolot but I can see that this is a bad argument. UBI advocates would respond that a UBI can 'become' functionally targeted because you increase marginal tax rates, and you can get around incentives by combining it with e.g. a negative income tax, or having the level be quire low (enough to live on but not very comfortably). My point isn't that a UBI is good and the authors are wrong, it's that the authors aren't interested in exploring plausible alternatives in good faith and don't explain why.
Thirdly, the authors have a common habit of pointing out problems and not positing clear alternatives or counterfactuals. For example in probably the worst chapter of the book they posit that current software development is (not necessarily on nett) harmful and antithetical to the original hacker ethos. This is because (they argue) big companies try to control software, and design software so that experts can use it and automate things. Aside from being completely contrary to my own experience as a software person (open source culturs is alive and well, hackers by and large I would say less interested than normal in like making stuff that can be used by non-technical people) it doesn't explain what actual "hacker approved" measures could have made things different. It seems to me that as companies like microsoft and apple create their own ecosystems and walled gardens hackers said "ok fine I'll do my own thing". Would hackers (or anyone) prefer it if... instead the government came along and said "no Microsoft you have to make software for noobs"? Surely not, so what are the authors even advocating? They don't say.
Finally, there's a lot of what feel like morte and bailey arguments. One of the problems the authors face is that some claims about technology are kind of obvious and not that interesting (e.g. tech + authoritarianism = bad), and the latter claims are really unclear and depend a lot on your values and/or how the future turns out (e.g. social media is bad). The authors seem to try to have their cake and eat it too by muddling things up, so that some type of technology is BAD FOR US in an INTERESTING/UNEXPECTED way, but where this is only true given their muddling. As an example, take the chapter on the Panama Canal. The point of the chapter is to demonstrate that big technological grand visions can be bad. But the failure of the Panama Canal is one of a grand vision coupled with abuses of state power (e.g. forced labor) and what would be at least today literal crimes (invester fraud). If you imagine a market context, something like what exists in Western Democracies, then it's not really clear grand visions are bad. Sure they will sometimes/often fail, but then they go out of business, investors lose money, people learn and we all move on.
The basic thesis of this book is: throughout history, technological progress is made to benefit the elite. Left to itself, there is no trickle down effect and the masses end up worse off than before the new technology appeared. However there have been times when societal forces (what we would call Samaj in India) have managed to force benefits to become more widespread.
Today we’re at such a juncture with two technologies - Green Energy and Artificial Intelligence. The book argues that we seem to be taking a more elitist path with AI compared to Green Energy. We could still change direction in both. Which path will we take?
Great book, that could change your mental model. The only drawback is that it is excessively focused on the USA (and, to a lesser extent, the UK) and makes only token references to the rest of the world. Still, the thesis is interesting and hence worth reading.
I really, really love Acemoglu and think his Nobel Prize is well deserved. I admire his style, his writing, and especially his ideas. What he says about technology and its failure to improve people’s lives over the past few decades really resonates with me. However, his proposed solutions and explanations aren’t entirely convincing to me. More government isn’t a cure-all for every problem.
In my view, the book has a clear progressive bias, and the authors aren’t trying to hide it. It feels nostalgic for a past era of progressive ideals. Meanwhile, the question of why the Industrial Revolution happened when and where it did—and why there hasn’t been another like it in recent times—remains up in the air.
You may like him or not, agree with him or not, but this book is a must-read.
Trump’ın 2. dönemi gelişmelerini de göz önünde bulundurunca iyice içinizi karartacak bir kitap ama çok anlaşılır ve neden sonuç ilişkileri kurabilme yeteneği olan herkes anlar. Yani ekonomi üatadı olmanıza gerek yok.
Özellikle Daniel Susskind’in “Çalışılmayan Bir Dünya” kitabında anlatıldığı gibi hiçbir şeyin günlük güneşlik devam etmeyeceğini iddia ediyor. önlem almazsak çalışanlar için dezavantajlı, tekno-zenginler ve güç sahibi politikacılar için bulunmaz bir silah haline gelen otomasyon sistemleri, yapay zeka, sosyal medya gibi araçları anlatıyor. Ama yüzeysel değil. Tarihsel gidişatı, özellikle otomasyonun etkileri üzerinden çok iyi anlatmış. Bu gelişmelerin şu ana kadarki olumsuz etkilerini “kader” olarak görmek yerine müdahale etmek gerekliliğinden bahsetmiş ama maalesef şu an ne liderler eski liderler ne işçi hareketi eskisi kadar güçlü, ne genel halk örgütlü.
یادداشتی به مناسبت خوانش آخرین اثر دارون عجم اغلو:
Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and Prosperity
کتاب قدرت و پیشرفت اثر مفصل عجم اغلو و سایمون جانسون، شاید یکی از مهمترین کُتبهای اقتصادِ عمومی دهه اخیر باشد. کتابی حاصلِ دغدغههای اخیر عجم اغلو یعنی، تکنولوژی و خصوصا هوش مصنوعی که به پشتوانه منابع مفصلش برای افراد علاقهمند به تکنولوژی بسیار اهمیت دارد. در اینفوگرافیک بالا، مهمترین نکات کتاب قدرت و پیشرفت را خلاصه کردم. و در ادامه مهمترین نکات کتاب را به زبان ساده آوردهام، هرچند باید کتاب به دقت خوانده شود تا این نکات به ذهن و جان خوانندگان بنشیند.
شاید بتوان مسئله اصلی کتاب را این پرسش مطرح کرد: آیا عواید فناوری به شکل مساوی به آحاد جامعه میرسد؟ کتاب سعی میکند با ادله فراوان به یک پاسخ روشن برای این سوال برسد. پاسخ کتاب این است: نه لزوما و شوربختانه در بیشتر تاریخ بشر عواید نشئت گرفته از فناوری تنها به گروه محدودی از جامعه رسیده است. کتاب به خوشبینی غولهای فناوری و مدیران و سهامداران شرکتهای دیجیتال مانند ماکروسافت، گوگل و متا (فیسبوک) میپردازد که معتقد اند مسیر فناوری امروز که در راستای توسعه هوشمصنوعی است، باعث میشود تا جامعه بهرهمندتر گردند. کتاب این فرضیه و خوشبینی را زیر سوال میبرد و نویسندگان کتاب معتقد اند که مسیرفعلی نوآوریهای دیجیتال باعث بیشترشدن شکاف طبقاتی در جامعه میشود و باید مسیر توسعه فناوری تغییر کند.
ارابه ناقص بهرهوری
یکی از کلیدیترین موضوعات کتاب زیر سوال بردن تئوری یا اثر Bandwagon productivity effect یا اثر ارابه بهرهوری است. بر اساس این تئوری با افزایش بهرهوری (که عمدتا به خاطر اتوماسیون صورت میپذیرد)، هزینهها کاهش مییابد، درآمد افراد افزایش مییابد و بر اساس آن عواید حاصل از بهرهوری به آحاد جامعه میرسد. عجم اغلو و سایمون جانسون نشان میدهند که به طور تاریخی این موضوع نمیتواند اثبات شود. و فناوریهایی که موجب بهرهوری میشوند خود به خود باعث این نخواهند شد که عواید حاصل از بهرهوری و کاهش هزینهها به آحاد جامعه برسد. اتفاقا، اتوماسیون حاصل از بهروری میتواند باعث دو قطبی شدن جامعه به لحاظ رفاه و بهرهمندی شود.
چشمانداز فناوری
کتاب بدون این که به شکل مستقیم به این پرسش مهم فلسفی پاسخ دهد که آیا فناوری Value-free است، در فصل دوم به طور کامل به این پرسش میپردازد. کتاب با مقایسه دو موردِ کانال سوئز و کانال پاناما نشان میدهد که چگونه یک فناوری بدون توجه به مسئله چشم انداز و اثرات جانبی آن میتواند باعث فاجعه شود. کتاب تاکید میکند که فناوری مسیر لاجرمی ندارد و توسط انسانها، هدایت میشود و این بدین معناست که انتخابهای ما انسانهاست که به فناوری جهت میدهد.
بهرهوری حاشیهای: توانمندسازی آحاد جامعه یا اتوماسیون نصف و نیمه (So-So Automation)
شاید یکی از مضامین اصلی کتاب پاسخ به این سوال باشد که در چه صورت ارابه بهرهوری رخ میدهد و آحادجامعه از فواید فناوری بهرهمند میشوند؟ پاسخ کتاب این است: زمانی که فناوری باعث شود تا به جای کنار گذاشتن آدمها، آنها توانمند شوند و برایشان فعالیتهای جدید و متنوع تعریف شود، آن وقت میتوان گفت که فناوری میتواند منجر به اثر ارابهای شود. کتاب در این جا به مفهوم مهمی به نام Marginal productivity اشاره میکند که به زبان ساده و ریاضی به این معنی است که اگر یک انسان به یک کسب و کار اضافه شود چقد به بهرهوری و خروجی آن کسب و کار اضافه میشود. کتاب به این حقیقت اشاره میکند که در صورتی که Marginal Productivity افراد یا بهرهوری حاشیهای کارکنانِ یک شرکت یا یک کارخانه افزایش پیدا کند، آن وقت کسب و کارها افراد بیشتری را استخدام میکنند و کسب و کارشان را گسترش میبخشند و مشاغل بیشتری ناشی از فناوری ایجاد میشود. اما در صورتی که فناوری باعث شود تا کارهای افراد دچار فرآیند اتوماسیون شود و فقط ماشینها جایگزین انسانها شوند و فعالیتهای جدید پدید نیایند، آن وقت بهرهوری حاشیهای افراد کاهش مییابد و افراد بیکار میشوند و عواید ناشی از بهرهوری فقط به صاحبان کسب و کارها و سهام دارها میشوند. این که به کارگیری فناوریها باعث شود تا توانمندسازی افراد و یا جایگزین شدنشان رخ دهد، تنها انتخاب ماست. کتاب همچنین به اثر اتوماسیون بر بهرهوری کلان سازمانها میپردازد. برای مثال، اگر به جای صندوقدار مغازهها از دستگاههای خودکار استفاده کنیم، تنها شغلها را از بین بردهایم و باعث بهرهوری کلان مغازهها نشدهایم، کتاب به این نوع اتوماسیون، اتوماسیون نصف و نیمه میگویند که تنها باعث بیکاری و پر پول شدن جیب مدیران و سهامداران شرکتها میشود.
یادگیری ماشینی یا کاربرد ماشینی
کتاب به سه دوره عصرکشاورزی و فناوریهای کشاورزی، عصر انقلاب صنعتی و عصر دیجیتال میپردازد. به طور خلاصه، کتاب نشان میدهد که در نیمه دوم عصر انقلاب صنعتی و نیمه نخست عصر دیجیتال به دلیل نهادهای مدنی، قدرتمند بودن نیروی کار و توضیح نسبتا متناسب قدرت میان کارگر و کارفرما مسیر فناوری به سمت توانمندسازی افراد و توزیع متوازن بهرهوری پیشرفته است. اتفاقی که در عصر دیجیتال امروز، رخ نمیدهد. در عصر دیجیتال امروز، ابزارهای دیجیتال به جای توانمندسازی کارکنان تبدیل به ابزارهایی برای کنترل آنها و کمتر کردن قدرتشان شده اند. همچنین فناوریهایی نظیر یادگیری ماشینی (هوش مصنوعی) باعث شده میشود تا افراد شغل خود را از دست بدهند بدون آن که بهرهوری به شکل کلان رخ دهد و این یعنی اتوماسیون نصف و نیمه. کتاب توصیه میکند تا به جای توجه به Machine Learning یا یادگیری ماشینی باید به Machine Usefulness یا کاربرد ماشینی توجه کرد. به این که چگونه باید فناوریهای گسترش یابند تا مکمل آدمی باشند به جای آن که باعث شوند افراد شغلشان را از دست دهند. همچنین کتاب میگوید فناوری یادگیری ماشینی یا هوش مصنوعی قادر نیست تا بسیاری از فعالیتهای مهم و تصمیمگیریهای اساسی را انجام دهند چرا که هوش آدمی یا مکانیزم تصمیمگیری آدمی بسیار مبتنی بر شرایط محیطی و شرایط اجتماعی است و دائما در حال تغییر است. بنابراین یادگیری ماشینی نمیتواند نویدبخش یک اتوماسیون گسترده با افزایش بهرهنوری خیرهکننده باشد و خوشبینی غولهای فناوری در این باره بسیار گمراه کننده است.
راه حل چیست؟
کتاب به مانند بسیاری از کُتُب مشابه دیگر، مثل کتابِ رقابت نوآوری دیجیتال که نگارنده ترجمه نموده، هدفش تشخیص و نه تجویز است. اما راهکارهای کتاب بعضا میتواند سرنخی باشد برای رسیدن به راهکارهای جامعتر. راهکارهایی مانند تقویت جامعهمدنی و توانمندسازی طبقه کارگر، مالیات بستن بر اتوماسیون، اعطای گرنت به پژوهشها و پروژههای تحقیقاتی در حوزه کاربردماشینی به جای یادگیری ماشینی، انحصارزدایی و شکستن شرکتهای بزرگ فناوری مانند گوگل، ماکروسافت و فیسبوک و توجه به مسئله آموزش از راهکارهای کتاب است. به طور کلی، کتاب با غنای عمیقی به مسئله فناوری و بهرهوری آن در طول تاریخ یک هزارساله اخیربشری میپردازد و درس آموزههای بسیاری برای آینده کوتاه مدت و میان مدت بشریت دارد.
This was a book club read I never would have picked up otherwise. And I'm so glad I did! I didn't have time to write a review immediately when I finished (as I normally do), which is a win in this case. A week after reading it, I can honestly say this book is actively influencing the way I think at the world around me (especially current events).
Anyway, this book provides an in-depth look at how technological progress affects societies and who has power in them - ranging from the canal digging machines used for the Suez and Panama canals to more recent developments in AI. At its core, it criticises the view that technological progress automatically means a better world, while maintaining that it can almost always result in a better world if the right choices are made about its use.
To absolutely nobody's surprise, a non-fiction book by 2 nobelprize winning economists makes for fairly dense reading, so I won't go into a more detailed description. The writing is more accessible than I'd expect, but it is simply a lot of information - they are nothing if not thorough in making their case. I'm convinced, and if you have any interest at all in the subject, you'll find it well worth the effort.
In “Power and Progress,” Acemoglu and Johnson convincingly make the case that technological progress has never been automatically associated with societal benefits (e.g., agricultural improvements in the Middle Ages were captured by nobles to build cathedrals, early factories in England made factory owners rich while workers became poorer and less healthy). Instead, whether new technologies benefit society at large depends on institutions and how power is shared in society.
Take Germany’s approach to automation in the car industry, for example. Unlike the US, Germany uses sectoral collective bargaining to set wages, which incentivizes companies to find ways to raise productivity compared to their peers and still pay workers the same amount as their peers, meaning that productivity increases translate to profit gains. Germany has actually embraced automation more than the US, but thanks to its sectoral unions, it has made efforts to retrain workers and reallocate them to new tasks, finding ways for technology to complement, not replace, workers. Technology-as-human-replacement can be inefficient and fails to take advantage of human workers’ flexibility and adaptability. As Elon Musk put it after unsuccessfully trying to fully automate the production of Teslas: “Humans are underrated.”
And yet, many companies are embracing automation regardless of the costs, widening inequality, worsening or hardly improving consumer experiences (e.g., automated help lines), surveilling workers, and hollowing out the skilled workforce.
Acemoglu and Johnson call for policy change to incentivize human-complementing technology developments and stop subsidizing AI, not halt technological progress altogether. Some ideas struck me as particularly effective (e.g., decreasing payroll taxes below taxes on capital to stop incentivizing automation, subsidizing technologies that increase the labor share of income, regulating digital privacy, investing in retraining programs).
The challenge will be how to continue to incentivize the very real societal benefits technological progress enables (e.g., better and more rapidly developed life-saving vaccines and drugs) with ensuring new technologies produce shared prosperity and do not worsen societal challenges (e.g., anti democratic forces, mass unemployment, growing inequality). Burdensome regulation and industrial policy are likely to be less effective than adjusting incentives away from automation toward productivity-increasing technologies (e.g., by taxing capital more heavily than labor, investing in research).
Regardless of whether you agree with Acemoglu and Johnson’s conclusions and recommendations, “Power and Progress” will challenge you and possibly inspire some optimism that we can still shape the effects of AI and other new technologies on our societies.
This was...surprising. Authors describe the problems of concentration and technology pointing out well the risks and problems. What is less convincing are the proposed solutions, what is a bit tiring is the too long historical intro. Also, small thjngs here and there - the echo chambers are ať least according to Bail not so much of a problem and I would expect the authors to confront this somehow.
Uluslarin dususu ve dar koridor gibi etkileyici bir kitap degil, ama yine de teknolojinin topluma etkisi uzerine mukemmel bir kitap. Ozellikle gunumuzde dijital teknolojilerin topluma etkileri, nasil toplum icin daha faydali hale gelebilecegi hakkinda pratik bilgiler de veriyor. Ayrica cok iyi bir arastirma var arkasinda. Kitabin sonu cok iyi, teknoloji devlerini elestiriyor. Ozellikle ilk bolumleri oldukca isci/toplum bakis acisini iceriyor. Bunu ekonomiye ve ulkelere etkilerini inceliyor, bunu da karsilastirmalar yaparak veriyor. Ilk bolumleri cok uzun buldum, bunlar kisalabilir. Ayrica tercume de cok iyi degil, cokca yazim hatasi da var.
Another thoughtful and well written book by Daron Acemoglu, this time co-authored with Simon Johnson. Power and Progress challenges the idea that the pace of technological change is inevitable and that it will lead to greater automation and job losses. Tracing the concepts from medieval times through the Industrial Revolution it shows how ‘countervailing forces’ such as protective legislation, organised labour and government intervention have balanced technological progress with societal well being. Bringing the notion up to date with the experience of big tech and the prospect of Generative AI, it argues for urgent measures to tackle this new threat to democracy, employment and humanity.
The authors’ arguments work when they discuss need for improved regulation and policy so that economies work smoother and prevent excess rent taking. But since they want their book to be about how technology is bad, they don’t focus there. In their own book there is plenty of evidence that humanity’s technology improvements - from axes and fire until today - is the reason we have the potential for longer and richer lives.
DNF at 35%. There was absolutely no need for this book to be so long. Read another review that said it reads like 'economists discover social power' and literally, that. Chapter 1 summarises a really basic thesis and the rest of the book is just repeating the same point with different historical examples.
Paired with Why Nations Fail, one wonders if Acemoglu’s strategy for getting readers to accept his theses is to grind them into submission—the chapters are needlessly long, meandering slogs that at times venture into territory that isn’t obviously connected to the book’s central arguments.
Those arguments—that technological advancements often don’t translate to widely shared prosperity and that the direction of technology is determined by the vision of elites—I found objectionable.
I reject the notion that the long-run direction of technology is determined by the choices and whims of elites—capital owners, executives, policymakers, etc. Rather, I think the evidence points to technology evolving convergently and semi-deterministically—i.e., similar technologies develop in response to similar conditions, needs, and pressures, independent of time, place, or the visions of specific individuals. Diamond (1997) touches on this in noting the independent development of technologies related to agriculture, metallurgy, and writing in isolated temporal and geographic contexts. Mokyr (1990) notes the independent invention of spinning wheels, looms, windmills, waterwheels, plows, and irrigation. Theorists like George Basalla (1988), Brian Arthur (2009), and Kevin Kelly (2010) paint portraits of new technologies emerging nigh-inevitably when requisite conditions and precursor technologies exist. Sure, historical, cultural, and institutional variation exists, and this leaves room for substantial divergence, but I think that convergence dominates the long-run, and doubly so in a globalized world of heightened competition.
I also think the authors’ contention that technological progress is only loosely associated with social progress suffers from a glaring oversight. The authors focus their attention pretty much exclusively on how new technologies shift the distribution of national wealth and income, noting that technical advances tend to displace workers and exacerbate inequality. They don’t, however, pay much attention to how technologies improve human welfare via new products. They claim that new technologies aren’t neatly associated with inclusive prosperity because they disproportionately benefit owners of capital over labor, but they overlook how new products benefit everyone as consumers. That is, the authors focus almost exclusively on how technology impacts production, but they largely neglect how it impacts consumption, resulting in a skewed and incomplete account of how technology contributes to progress. Capital income shares and real wages are important dimensions of a complete picture, for sure, but it’s hard to deny that technology has been an overwhelming net boon when life expectancy has doubled and vaccination, electricity, running water, refrigeration, automobiles, radio, television, personal computing, mobile telecommunication, etc., etc.—all products—have gone from non-existent to ubiquity.
Ultimately, I perceived the work as techno-pessimist. My issue with this pessimism is that I don’t think technology per se should be indicted in discussions of the perennial tension between capital owners and labor or the tradeoffs between innovation and displacement. In my view, such discussions and the concerns raised by the book are more appropriately framed as matters of economic culture and institutional milieu than as a matter of the rightness or wrongness of the “direction” of technology.
Progress is never automatic. Throughout the book, from the prologue to the concluding chapter, Daron Acemoglu and Simon Johnson reiterate this central message. Our intuition thinking otherwise reflects a misguided vision–a utopia promised and powered by new technologies.
This is not a technosceptic’s testimony. Unlike some proponents of AI regulations, such as Max Tegmark and Sam Altman, the economists are concerned with the labour setting disrupted by an unsupervised trend of innovation.
The authors cite the malnourishment of the mediaeval English farmers, defying our expectation on their long list of innovations. Similarly, they explore how the Industrial Revolution was initially a continuation of deplorable labour arrangement. The ‘technology bandwagon’ only rings true up to the first word, because no one beside some entitled cliques can jump on it.
This illusion is just as prevalent today as ever. It is unlikely that artificial intelligence is taking away troubles, but first and foremost, jobs. In other words, ‘Hillbilly Elegy’ is just as plausible as the ones in ‘I, Robot’ and ‘Brave New World’, the former and the residents thereof aptly foreshadowing a bleak future.
Think of ‘so-so automations’, such as digital check-ins. You’ll run into your boss on a Friday evening just before you go, not coincidentally because the app has tracked and predicted your business hour patterns. The power of the powerless is being chipped away.
As you progress through chapters four to eight, the authors gradually convince the reader that misdirected advancement is fundamentally dystopian. However, while their analysis has posed a veritable challenge to the prevailing vision, they did not chart a course against it in the coming chapters.
They propose the use of automation to assist manpower, but whether such a coalescence wastes human resources would have rightly bugged the late David Graebar. In that case, policymakers may turn to digital and automation taxes and dismantle tech giants. All this brashness underscores a key message: any interventions serve not to hamper the economy, better still, they steer it away from unintended consequences.
In spite of that, these solutions are not a proper response to their keen emphasis on ‘visions’ early on. While both policies and visions can undo or avert the wrongdoings, the bottom-up vision clearly has far-reaching impacts and is harder to spur into existence without guidance.
What they prize as the ultra determinant in Industrial Britain is an aspirant middle class following the Glorious Revolution. So within the bounds of the law, how to spark off a society-wide discourse above the pecking order remains unanswered. They briefly mentioned investigative journalism, a public sphere and some crowdfunded unions, all feasible until you meet the countries where the right to assemble is abridged, all bets are off.
Institutions that promote diverse opinions are well within the research field of the veteran economists. If not a roadmap, maybe a list of actionable steps for individuals would suffice? Robert J. Shiller developed a similar thesis in his 2019 book ‘Narrative Economics’, but apparently, his ‘narrative’ didn’t take off. It is hoped that this visionary book will not suffer the same irony.
Overall, they have studied widely and dispelled the digital utopian vision that riddles contemporary discourse. Even though the proposed solutions may not be a full answer to the challenge, the book nonetheless puts some policies in perspective as an attempt.
Creo que es importante comenzar mencionando que lo que muchas personas dicen en otros comentarios es cierto, este libro pudo haber sido un poco más corto. Habiendo dicho eso, yo disfruté de la totalidad del libro tanto en el aspecto de aprendizaje como en la sencilla curiosidad por los ejemplos y casos de estudio presentados por los autores. Es un libre interesante, sí, toca temas políticos, económicos, sociales, entre otros, pero lo hace de una manera coherente, fácil de seguir y ejemplificando sus puntos de una muy buena manera. En cuanto al aprendizaje en es te libro, debo decir que soporta una tesis que yo ya tenía conmigo con anterioridad y un poco como una cámara de eco, cada capítulo me llevaba a confirmar más esa tesis. Debo mencionar que los autores terminan con una aproximación mucho más optimista que yo, y esto podría ser una decepción pero entiendo de donde vienen y por qué piensan que sí hay una salida a un futuro lleno de "progreso tecnológico" que represente solo sufrimiento para lo que llamamos "el ciudadano de a pie". Esa es un poco la reflexión cínica que me llevo del libro, cada capítulo ayudó a cimentar más la idea y me da más bagaje para discutir al respecto y para conversar con otros. También me deja una reflexión sobre la productividad, la organización social colectiva y la participación en política. Creo que es un libro que más personas deberían leer, o por lo menos aproximarse a sus ideas.
A bit of a disappointment. More biased than I expected at the start, and a definition of progress tailored to support their ideas. The book is interesting, good collection of data and evolution, but is perhaps not the book you would expect after their previous collaborations.
PS: It may age badly because of their predictions about AI. Which are only in the last part of the book, not a big part of the good content in general.
For me this book opened the doors to the understanding of the current technology dynamics and what are the implications of the visions driving investments and development in technology. Sometimes technical about economics and politics but necessary. Sometimes partial. But overall great pice of research; putting together knowledge about politics, economics, psychology, philosophy and history.
I found it so often so surprising how progressive they think. I liked the final part of the more concrete policy suggestions! But overall, the book was to complex and sometimes hard to follow. (Jumping between examples and conclusion.) Overall, very interesting! But took me forever to go through it.
Yazarların çözümlere ilişkin düzen içi burjuva çözümlerine katılmasam da konunun temelini anlamak için doğru bir kitap. Konu ile ilgilenenlere tavsiye ederim. Önünüze konu ile okunacak bir çok kaynak da çıkaracaktır.
Left me worried about our love for big tech and AI in particular. AI might bring huge fortunes to some, but for most in its current direction it will create more inequality. I would say those calling for regulation and codes of ethics etc are on the right path.